Transcript of Question & Answer Session The Financial System and Monetary Policy in Australia
Timo Henckel
Thank you very much, Chris, for a sweeping overview of the Australian financial system and monitoring policy. One of the wonderful aspects of these events, of course, is that you get a chance to ask questions of people that you perhaps in different circumstances wouldnt be able to. So well have about 20 minutes for Q&A. If you can just briefly identify yourself and then ask a short and succinct question and hopefully we will get through as many as possible. For those of you who are wondering, my name is Timo Henckel. I am also a Faculty member of the Research School of Economics here and a colleague of … I know Bob is also going to ask a question so he is my fallback option if it remains quiet for too long. Robbie, would you like to ask a question?
Questioner
Thanks, Chris. So in my understanding there is - youve got Australian, Norway. Youve got a dominant transmission mechanism that goes through households. Households and … know that, I would suggest that households who are making decisions based on … if theyre making decisions based on … likely dont even know that every first Tuesday of most months you say grace and theyre not going to be - I wouldnt think that theyre going to have an Alex … or somebody like that telling them ration … this. Does that influence the way we would think would be an optimal RBA Board, given its households that are in first order affected? Does that influence, in your mind, the way we think? Would the RBA Board then so fully … representative, something that would provide confidence to households, rather than macro economists? Were basically looking at - for actions, functions and trying to figure out what type of guidance would transmit the best - the most accurate action or function?
Christopher Kent
Yes. Quite a bit in there, Robbie. I mean, even the US they know even less about the Feds decisions. When our decisions happen, especially nowadays, the Governor gets up in front of a pack of media. She usually is on all the commercial stations, on radio, in the press, of course everyone doesnt - thats not the only way people get their news. In the US that just doesnt happen. I think there still is a really important role, and most of forward guidance probably is focusing, not on the individuals in the economy who arent necessarily that well informed about these things or they have a temporary attention to them but markets. That they translate them into whats the rate on the term deposit at a bank for two or three years or six months or whatever it may be. Whats the rate on a bond for corporate or long-term - a government bond that someone who has money might buy one flows. What are the sticker rates for a household thats about to go and borrow a variable rate versus, say, a one, two or three-year fixed term loan in Australia. So I think it is really important to recognise, I think as you suggest, theres a limitation in how much the general populous are going to absorb from this, which is one argument why the central bank doesnt need to necessarily speak to them and what my former colleague Guyger Bell said, speak to the markets, not necessarily through formal guidance but by having a clear and well understood reaction function and then the markets can do that interpretation thats quite important.
Timo Henckel
So were keeping order, so far over there, over there and then well get -
Christopher Kent
If I keep my answers long enough, Bob will have to ask me one of his really hard questions on the side. Dont worry, Bob, well get to you. Yes.
Questioner
You were … in your talk that essentially the effect size of … is the same across Australia and the US, despite the very different composition of our mortgage markets. If Australia were to adopt a secondary mortgage market which is normally, as I understand it, given thats the reason why the US has such a hard share of fixed rate mortgages, so if Australia were to introduce about equivalent of a … do you think that would have an impact on the effect of our cash flow monetary policy or do you think it would simply change the way the transmission …
Christopher Kent
Yeah. Well, again, I think the results, and I call them out and there are others who have studied using our own model, sort of trying to weigh up the contributions of these different transmission channels overall. Even though I like other Australians focused a lot on the cash flow channel in my talk this evening, its actually one of the smaller contributors to the overall transmission. So if were changing that bit, it might not make much difference. Im not convinced its all about Fanny and Freddy in the US. I think partly theyve come about for various reasons but the US - one reason why really long fixed rate mortgages are very attractive in the US, apart from it protects households from interest rates but remember they have to pay a margin. Someone has to cover that interest rate risk on the other side. So its not free, sort of, insurance for that mortgage holder. But one of the reasons is because of the tax system. Your own home mortgage is tax deductible in the US. So you dont want to pay-off fast. Right. So a fixed rate suits that. Its not true in Australia. Your own mortgage is not tax deductible so you do want to pay that off quite quickly and thats why we have these offset and redraw accounts. Thats why people, if they fix, they tend not to fix them for too long because they like to be able to pay that down and there is some way of self-insuring against interest rate risk. Right. If you do that over a long period of time and you get ahead of the mortgage after a couple of years many households are able to do that. You can absorb a lot of the interest rate risk and you dont have to pay someone else to do it for you.
Timo Henckel
Weve got another question over here.
Questioner
Is there a disproportionate effect of tightening monetary policy on those of lower income? And if there is, how do we balance the wider objective of our inflation target with the needs of lower income people?
Christopher Kent
Yeah. Its a good question and its been looked at, you know, over a period of time. I guess the first thing is, I would emphasise when youre sort of thinking about the burden of higher interest rates directly, Im not sure that lower income people pay that because the lowest of the low income households typically dont have - not only do they not have a mortgage, they dont even get qualified for a credit card perhaps. The lowest of the low income households. The other thing we know is that lower income households find it much more difficult to protect themselves against inflation for various reasons, partly because of the assets they hold. If they dont hold housing or they dont have equities they suffer quite a bit there. So I think thats one thing. And then, you know, I think monetary policy is quite focused, one, on inflation which penalises everyone, but I would argue penalises those on lower incomes more. It also focuses very much on employment and a lack of employment is usually going to penalise those in society who have the least income and the most to lose.
Questioner
Chris, could you put up the first slide for me, please?
Christopher Kent
So many slides.
Questioner
Yeah, the first one.
Christopher Kent
Yeah, Ill get there. That one.
Questioner
…
Christopher Kent
That one. Sorry.
Questioner
So I like all the … but I sort of lost the structure. So when I just look at this picture and I want to draw a slightly different conclusion. So over this picture I see the RBA. I see the fair. I see other central banks. And if I understand it rightly you subject all these country morals to the same shop. The thing that really strikes you about that is lets look at how there is something about Australia, if Ive interpreted this right, that means we get very little outlook changes, is that my interpretation?
Christopher Kent
No. So, look, I think -
Questioner
Or does it mean the variance is small? I mean -
Christopher Kent
Yeah. Look, I think its tricky, Bob, and its because were not comparing - its not quite an apples on apples comparison. Its a little bit an apples and orange comparison. And so what do I mean by that? So the blue range is the range that is given by different central estimates of different models and we dont have many that weve thrown in for Australia and they happen to sit quite close to each other. The US has more and then the other central banks weve done a bit of a cheat on because Ive bundled them together so the graph doesnt spread right out and Ive got quite a few different ones. Theyre not too far away from each other but there are some models which are outliers, which is why you get a higher and a lower end. The central black points arent that far apart is the key point.
Questioner
So let me interpret it the way I want to interpret it.
Christopher Kent
Sure, go ahead.
Questioner
And then Ill ask the question. Lets suppose I thought that the RBA outlook effect was minus 0.4. And let me suppose that the other central banks was around about 98. Right. And now I take the midpoints of inflation and I get the same sort of thing. That other central banks … effective on inflation. So the question I want to ask then was I want to say that this looks as though monetary policy is less …
Christopher Kent
I think -
Questioner
Rather than all the same. And then the second question that I want to ask is if that was true, what does that imply about two questions. Question number 1 is suppose you wanted to make monetary policy more effective, then you would go through each one of your propositions and you would say, if I change this I could do that. And the second question is, if its true that monetary policies are less effective, what does that imply for the balance of … monetary policy … that is its true that monetary policy was less effective. Then it suggests that in Australia you want to put a link … more emphasis on the fiscal policy. Or alternatively you would try and beef up the monetary policy. So is that question still clear or -
Christopher Kent
Ill do my best, Rob. I feel like Im battling one of your excellent study sessions where wed sit around your office and pose lots of complex questions but I think - I think - I guess what Im asserting in the paper but not showing particularly well in the graph, because of the way its constructed, is these differences arent so great and part of what looks visually to be quite different. Youre suggesting that there might be one effect, lets say in one of the other -
Questioner
Im suggesting this graph sets up entirely different …
Christopher Kent
But - and Im just trying to dissuade you from that but Ill entertain your point later in a sec but if you - if youre wanting to pick, say, one of the more extreme ends on output, lets for example of one of the other central banks and you picked a 0.8, but that central bank might have two models and one model might give you a minus 0.8 and the other model might be at the top end of it. Right. And so because Ive got more models in there, more economies in there, it tends - its spanning quite big. So thats a little bit of it. Let me try a different way.
Questioner
Its …
Christopher Kent
Yeah. Let me try and suggest a different way of thinking about it though, which is how I first came to this and then we went and looked at the models. If you look over a period of time, even in this episode, the differences in the volatility of inflation and output havent been so tremendous across many economies, unless theyve gone and had a financial crisis. Thats a bit different. And the amplitude of the policy tool has not been that different either. So if the shocks have been similar and the policy therefore has been responding in a similar way, you sort of have to say the effectiveness of that policy is similar across central banks. So thats a different way of thinking about it.
Questioner
… central bank …
Christopher Kent
No.
Questioner
…
Christopher Kent
No. I mean, it might suggest the shocks are common or - and were not talking about shocks always being at the same time and then there are some really big shocks where its really important, right, particularly in, say, the GFC and were a small open economy so big shocks offshore matter a lot for us so were responding often inkind. Yes. So I think thats - Im not sure that you can go and sort of play with the channels and engineer the economy to be quite different. I mean, I would argue just that monetary policy has been similarly effective overall across these economies but theyre facing different economies and again its like somehow underneath the hood everything runs a bit differently and the engines arent all exactly the same but they basically get you to where you need to get in about the same time. Of course, the other thing central banks are doing all the time is trying to get a lot of feedback. So when theyre changing rates theyre looking at the effect of these and theyre looking back in the past and theyre trying to come to judgments whether they need to do a little bit more or a little bit less. But its often - yeah. Its often just set in Australia and its been asserted by people, you know, because of the cash flow channel monetary policy just hits that much harder. Well, it does hit some households hard but they manage it okay.
Questioner
Theres no -
Christopher Kent
And then there are these other channels. Yeah.
Questioner
Thank you.
Christopher Kent
Thank you for finding my most confusing graph.
Timo Henckel
One more question over there.
Questioner
Thanks. Chris, I just had one question. You mentioned Norway earlier, and please correct me if Im misconstruing your comments earlier, but you mentioned that similar composition in terms of variable rate mortgage were a high proportion but also using forward guidance which add a significant amount of backlash here but you seem to indicate that less of that had occurred in Norway. Was there a - like a quantitative reason for that … more conservative thing or was it more something about the Australian obsession?
Christopher Kent
Its a good question and when I was sort of writing this I sort of came to Norway a bit late in the piece and added it in some of the charts late and I did wonder that same question. Im quite familiar with the US economy and having lived there over the years, familiar with the way they respond or dont respond and the general public dont know when the Fed meets and what theyve done, in a way thats not true here. Im not sure if thats the case in Norway. The comment was the Norwegian central bank doesnt think its a problem for their credibility and its been argued here that it could be a problem for us and that may well be so. So, yeah, its a good question. Are they as obsessed as we are about all things to do with variable rate mortgages.
Timo Henckel
Weve got another question here.
Questioner
In the US theres some discussion about whether the central bank actually knows more about the economic market and there was discussion about the forward guidance. So Im wondering how does RBA perceive itself, like you know if you can discuss … your discussion with the forward guidance. Would you …
Christopher Kent
Yeah. Its a really good question and a former colleague at the central bank, Peter Tulip, and others looked at this exact sort of question. And I believe part of the answer is that central banks, and were the same, arent much better forecasters than anyone else. Theres no real secret source they have anymore. Maybe in the past when data was that much harder to come by and that much less timely they had some readings that might have been advantageous. That doesnt seem to be the case. So when you compare our forecast to things like consensus economic forecasts, were not that much better or worse than the sort of consensus forecasts for GDP. I think it turns out we were slightly better on inflation, particularly in the near term. So for some reason we do seem to have some good insight there. Again, that might disappear over time as theres more and more timely data provided on reflection. So I dont think its the case of knowing more and therefore we can benefit everyone if we get our forward guidance out there. But forward guidance can still play a role and I think some central banks use forward guidance as well to help inform people about their reaction function and as they - my colleague Guyger Bell used to argue its the reaction function is really key. Thank you.
Timo Henckel
Weve got time for maybe one or two more questions.
Questioner
Im not going to be very academically rigorous here so feel free to throw the baby out of the bath whenever you want. But theres been a - it filters though at least theres a bit of talk throughout hope and the like that monetary fiscal policy went opposite directions. There also appears to be a bit of talk in the US with the Fed losing some of its neutrality. How important do you think central bank neutrality is?
Christopher Kent
Well, central bank independence, I guess, I think it is very important and I think its been incredibly beneficial in helping to anchor inflation for a long period of time. And then inflation wasnt anchored, arguably there was some really big shocks. Arguably policy-makers, both fiscal and monetary, not just here but around the world, didnt anticipate just how quickly wed come out of COVID and how much stimulus was in the system, including piles of savings that many households and businesses were sitting on and various stimulatory interest rates. But monetary policy tends to be more responsive and it responded fairly quickly and fiscal policy has taken many different paths around the world. And a lot of the influence, not all but a lot of the influence, the reason why we had higher inflation was supply shocks which were persistent but not that persistent and some of them have sort of come out of the system. But I think monetary policy independence is really important. I think thats widely recognised because one of the reasons why inflation was able to come down more quickly, you could argue, is because inflation expectations were reasonably well anchored. And you could see that if you looked at wage outcomes in Australia because when inflation was pretty high, right, a lot of enterprise bargaining agreements are multiple geared ones so theyll make an agreement for two or three years but theyll specify a different rate. And so when inflation was really high often they were looking for a high rate and got a high rate in that first year but in subsequent years there was a recognition inflation would be coming down, just as we said it would, just as others were forecasting and so those wage outcomes were lower. There were lots of those sorts of behaviours evident around the world and I think anchoring inflation expectation is critical and monetary policy independence is important for that.
Timo Henckel
Time for one more quick question, if anyone still would like to get one in. Okay. One last final question there, please, and then well wrap up.
Questioner
So if we think that the cash flow channel is quite big, then given the social understanding that lots of people suffer when mortgage rates go up, doesnt this effectively argue that from a policy perspective we should want something more like fixed rates? Because if its not … monetary policy its got … but either lots of people arent hurting and we should just say … through this role or were doing something thats quite … for not a lot of monetary policy benefit.
Christopher Kent
Yeah. Maybe but I think this has been thought of more in the US where they have fixed rates and they point out the cost over the life of a mortgage of paying someone else for the insurance in fixing your rate because its not for free, especially in the US because you can also refinance and get lower rates, but when rates go up no-one refinances, as I suggested, to get a higher rate. And so theres a premium that someone in the market who is taking on that burden, of providing that insurance for you, in fixing your rate for 30 years is charging you. So I think you have to sort of weigh off these different costs and I guess what Im suggesting here is Australian households for various reasons turn out to be self-insurers but when they can see a bargain, right, many of them were very sadly and got very low rates when the banks offered low fixed rates partly out of our policies during the pandemic. So would we be better off with fixed rates? Maybe but we dont know because theyre not on offer here. Right. You can get them for two, three years but we dont have an institution set up, as was suggested earlier, like in the US to provide 30-year mortgages but theyre set up partly because of the tax treatment of the mortgage is very different.
Timo Henckel
Great. Thank you very much. Thank you, all, for coming and for some nice probing questions and, of course, thank you, Chris, for delivering the lecture.