RDP 2008-09: A Term Structure Decomposition of the Australian Yield Curve Appendix B: Risk-neutral Bond Pricing
December 2008
- Download the Paper 579KB
Here we examine why bonds should be priced under the risk-neutral measure. To simplify the analysis we work with a single factor model, that is
where all variables are scalars.
Consider the probability space with associated filtration taken as the augmented filtration of (see, for example, Steele 2001). Xt is an Ito process if
for μx and σx adapted to . Ito's lemma then states that for any function F(x,t) such that F is twice differentiable in x and differentiable in t,
Applying Ito's lemma to Equation (B1) we trivially get
Now let PA(rt,t) and PB(rt,t) denote the time t price of two zero-coupon bonds with different maturity dates. Then by Ito's lemma, Pi (i = A, B) will satisfy
Consider a portfolio that is long one A bond and short h B bonds. At time t this portfolio has value
If held for dt, the portfolio's value changes by
Hence we can make the portfolio instantaneously riskless by choosing h = σA/σB. In this case, the portfolio must earn the risk-free rate rt and so
Substituting Equations (B6) and (B7) into Equation (B8) and setting h = σA/σB leads to
or
Hence the ratio (μ − rtP)/σ is independent of the choice of bond, and so there must exist a function λr such that
holds for any bond price P.
Now substituting μ and σ as identified by Equations (B4) and (B5) into Equation (B9) results in a Black-Scholes type partial differential equation
which is solved subject to appropriate boundary conditions (bonds pay 1 unit at maturity) and the radiation condition P → 0 as r → ∞.
The Feynman-Kac formula then says that the solution to Equation (B10) is given
where rt satisfies
and is standard Brownian motion in the risk-neutral measure associated with