RBA Annual Conference – 2011 Productivity: The Lost Decade Saul Eslake[*]

1. Introduction

‘Productivity’ is, at its simplest, a measure of how effectively or efficiently a workplace, a business or government agency, a region or a nation as a whole uses the resources at its disposal to produce goods and services which are in turn valued, in some way, by those who consume or use them. At the level of individual workplaces or firms, productivity measures are often expressed in terms of output per unit of a single factor of production, such as land or livestock (in agriculture), some measure of ore extracted (in mining), or, in manufacturing and services businesses, some measure of labour input such as person-hours. At more aggregated or economy-wide levels, productivity is usually expressed as a measure of value added (such as gross product) either per unit of labour input (labour productivity) or per unit of labour and capital services inputs (multifactor productivity). While, conceivably, other factors of production could be included in measures of multifactor productivity, including environmental factors such as water or energy, to date these have been extremely rare, but they may become more widely used as the policy focus on the use of finite natural resources (and their price) increases.

Economists have long recognised that productivity is a Good Thing (in the Sellar and Yeatman (1930) sense) as the most important source of improvements in material living standards. Book I of Smith (1937) is, arguably, a treatise on the contribution of advances in labour productivity achieved through better organisation of work (‘the division of labour’):

[T]en persons … could make among them upwards of forty-eight thousand pins in a day. Each person, therefore, making a tenth part of forty-eight thousand pins, might be considered as making four thousand eight hundred pins in a day. But if they had all wrought separately and independently, and without any of them having been educated to this peculiar business, they certainly could not each of them have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day; that is, certainly, not the two hundred and fortieth, perhaps not the four thousand eight hundredth part of what they are at present capable of performing, in consequence of a proper division and combination of their different operations.

(Smith 1937, p 5)

Book II deals with the way in which the accumulation of capital contributes to higher labour productivity:

As the accumulation of stock is previously necessary for carrying on this great improvement in the productive powers of labour, so that accumulation naturally leads to this improvement. The person who employs his stock in maintaining labour, necessarily wishes to employ it in such a manner as to produce as great a quantity of work as possible. He endeavours, therefore, both to make among his workmen the most proper distribution of employment, and to furnish them with the best machines which he can either invent or afford to purchase. His abilities in both these respects are generally in proportion to the extent of his stock, or to the number of people whom it can employ. The quantity of industry, therefore, not only increases in every country with the increase of the stock which employs it, but, in consequence of that increase, the same quantity of industry produces a much greater quantity of work. (Smith 1937, p 260)[1]

Krugman (1992, p 9) wrote that ‘[a] country's ability to improve its standard of living over time depends almost entirely on its ability to raise its output per worker’.

This sentiment has been echoed more recently by Australia's most senior policy-makers and advisers. For example, Stevens (2009) identifies productivity as the only real basis for optimism about future income and more recently ‘there is only one source of ongoing higher rates of growth of real per capita incomes, and that is higher rates of growth of productivity’ (Stevens 2011), while Parkinson (2011, pp 11–12) observed that ‘[i]n the long run, productivity growth – producing more from the same inputs – is the only sustainable way for future generations to enjoy higher living standards’.

At the RBA Conference a decade ago, Australia's productivity performance was widely celebrated. Bean (2000, p 90) observed that ‘[u]nderpinning Australia's good economic performance over the last decade has been a high rate of productivity growth, both in historical terms and relative to other countries’. At the same Conference, Forsyth (2000, p 236) also noted that ‘Australia's productivity growth had been amongst the most rapid [of a number of countries experiencing high productivity growth] in recent years’. Both authors attributed Australia's strong productivity growth performance largely to microeconomic or structural reforms, although Bean in particular warned that, on the basis of earlier UK experience with productivity-enhancing reforms, ‘Australian policy-makers and households would be unwise to project the recent high rates of productivity growth into the future’ (2000, p 101). Bean's note of caution was, as it turned out, especially perspicacious.

2. Australia's Productivity Performance in the 2000s

Australia's productivity performance, however measured, has deteriorated substantially since the late 1990s. In terms of simple decade-average comparisons:

  • Labour productivity for the Australian economy as a whole grew at an average annual rate of 1.5 per cent over the ten years to 2009/10 (or 1.4 per cent per annum using the Australian Bureau of Statistics' (ABS) ‘quality-adjusted’ estimates for hours worked), compared with 2.1 per cent per annum over the ten years to 1999/2000, 1.4 per cent per annum over the ten years to 1989/90 and 2.8 per cent per annum over the ten years to 1979/80.
  • Multifactor productivity for the Australian economy as a whole was unchanged over the course of the 2000s (or declined at a 0.2 per cent average annual rate using ‘quality-adjusted’ hours worked), compared with growth averaging 1.6 per cent per annum in the 1990s, 0.7 per cent per annum in the 1980s and 1.5 per cent per annum in the 1970s;[2]
  • Labour productivity for 12 of the industry components of the ‘market sector’ (that is, excluding sectors in which productivity growth is notoriously difficult to measure, in particular public administration & safety, education & training, and health care & social assistance) for which the ABS has estimates going back before 1994/95 grew at an average annual rate of 1.9 per cent during the 2000s, compared with 2.6 per cent in the 1990s and 1.6 per cent in the 1980s; and
  • Market sector multifactor productivity grew at an average annual rate of 0.2 per cent in the 2000s, compared with 1.4 per cent in the 1990s.

Growth in all the above measures of productivity deteriorated as the 2000s progressed (see Figure 1 which presents growth in the above four series over rolling five-year periods). In particular, multifactor productivity growth was negative during the second half of the past decade.

Figure 1: Productivity Growth

In order to abstract from the influence of the business cycle on measured productivity growth, trends in productivity are more appropriately compared across ‘productivity growth cycles’ (see, for example, Productivity Commission (2010, p 58)). These of course don't coincide neatly with calendar decades. Nonetheless, comparisons across these cycles tell a similar story:

  • Growth in market sector labour productivity decelerated from an average of 3.3 per cent per annum over the productivity growth cycle which ran from 1993/94 through 1998/99, to 1.2 per cent per annum over the cycle which ran from 2003/04 through 2007/08 (or to 0.8 per cent per annum if the four additional market sectors for which the ABS publishes estimates from 1995/96 onwards are included), while in the as yet incomplete cycle, which began in 2008/09, labour productivity growth has averaged 1.5 per cent per annum.
  • Growth in market sector multifactor productivity slowed from an average of 2.1 per cent per annum in the 1993/94 through 1998/99 cycle to −0.3 per cent per annum in the 2003/04 through 2007/08 cycle (or to −0.8 per cent per annum including the four additional market sectors), and has averaged −1.0 per cent per annum in the as yet incomplete cycle, which began in 2008/09.

As shown in Figure 2, productivity growth during the most recent completed cycle was, on either measure, the worst of any cycle since the 1970s.

Figure 2: Productivity Growth Cycles

Australia has been by no means unique in experiencing a slowdown in productivity growth since the turn of the century. Of the 25 countries for which the OECD has estimates going back to 1990, only 4 experienced faster labour productivity growth in the 2000s than in the 1990s, those 4 being Israel, Switzerland, Turkey and the United States. And the decline in Australia's labour productivity growth rate between the 1990s and 2000s was of the same magnitude − 0.8 percentage points – as the unweighted average for the 26 countries for which it is possible for such comparisons to be made.

However, whereas Australian labour productivity growth was in line with the (unweighted) OECD average in the 1990s, during the 2000s it was, at 1.3 per cent per annum (according to the OECD's estimates), 0.5 percentage points below the unweighted OECD average and 0.2 percentage points below the weighted OECD average. Australia ranked 11th out of 25 OECD countries in descending order of labour productivity growth in the 1990s, and 17th out of 34 countries in the 2000s (see Table 1).

Table 1: Labour and Multifactor Productivity Growth Rates
Australia and other countries
Labour productivity Multifactor productivity
% per annum Difference % per annum Difference
1990–2000 2000–2010 1990–2000 2000–2009
Australia 2.1 1.3 −0.8   1.1 −0.7 −1.7
Austria   1.2     1.1 0.4 −0.7
Belgium 2.3 0.5 −1.8   0.6 −0.5 −1.2
Canada 1.8 0.9 −1.0   0.5 −0.7 −1.1
Chile   2.6     0.7 −0.8(a) −1.5
Czech Republic   3.5     −0.7 1.9(a) 2.6
Denmark 1.9 0.6 −1.3   0.4 −0.8 −1.2
Estonia   4.8     3.4 2.5(a) −0.9
Finland 3.0 1.5 −1.5   1.9 1.1 −0.7
France 2.0 0.8 −1.2   0.4 −0.4 −0.9
Germany 2.3 0.9 −1.4   1.4 0.1 −1.3
Greece 1.7 1.5 −0.2   0.1 0.0 −0.1
Hungary   2.9     0.8 0.9(a) 0.1
Iceland 1.0 2.6 1.7   0.4 2.4 2.1
Ireland 4.7 2.0 −2.8   2.9 −0.7 −3.6
Israel 0.5 1.2 0.7   0.2 0.4 0.2
Italy 1.5 0.0 −1.5   0.5 −1.1 −1.6
Japan 2.1 1.6 −0.6   −0.1 0.2 0.3
Luxembourg 2.1 0.2 −1.9   0.9 −0.6 −1.5
Mexico   0.3     0.1 −0.7(a) −0.8
Netherlands 2.1 0.7 −1.4   0.7 0.1 −0.6
New Zealand 1.3 1.1 −0.2   0.1 −0.6 −0.7
Norway 2.8 0.7 −2.1   1.8 −0.9 −2.7
Poland   3.2     3.4 0.7(a) −2.7
Portugal 3.7 1.1 −2.5   0.1 −1.1 −1.2
Slovak Republic   4.5     2.6 3.6(a) 1.1
Slovenia   2.6     1.2 0.9(a) −0.3
South Korea 5.6 4.3 −1.2   2.9 1.9 −1.0
Spain 1.4 1.1 −0.3   −0.1 −0.8 −0.7
Sweden 2.4 1.6 −0.7   0.9 0.2 −0.7
Switzerland 0.3 0.8 0.5   0.1 0.0 −0.1
Turkey 1.8 3.7 2.0   −0.8 −1.0 −0.2
United Kingdom 2.7 1.2 −1.5   1.4 −0.1 −1.5
United States 1.8 2.2 0.4   0.7 0.3 −0.4

Note: (a) 2000–2008

Sources: Conference Board (2011); OECD; author's calculations

Using the United States as a crude proxy for ‘best practice’ in terms of labour productivity,[3] the level of Australian labour productivity declined from a peak of 91.6 per cent of the corresponding US level in 1998 to 84.2 per cent of the US level in 2010, more than reversing the 5 percentage point increase in this ratio which occurred between 1990 and 1998. The 2010 level of this ratio was the lowest since 1973 (see Figure 3).

Figure 3: Australian Labour Productivity

Of the 28 OECD countries for which the Conference Board (2011) publishes data on what it calls ‘total factor productivity’ up to 2009, only 3 experienced faster multifactor productivity growth in the 2000s than in the 1990s (Israel and, perhaps counter-intuitively, Japan and, even more so, Iceland[4]). However, the decline in Australia's multifactor productivity growth rate as measured in the Conference Board database, of 1.7 percentage points (from 1.1 per cent per annum to −0.7 per cent per annum) was more than double the (unweighted) average for these 28 countries, and larger than any except those recorded in Finland, Ireland, Malta and Norway.

3. Causes of the Deterioration in Australia's Productivity Performance

3.1 ‘Sectoral’ explanations

Official explanations of the deterioration in Australia's productivity performance have tended to emphasise the contribution of especially sharp declines in productivity in three sectors of the economy: agriculture, forestry & fishing; mining; and electricity, gas, water & waste services (‘utilities’). For example, the Productivity Commission (2010, p 68) estimates that these three sectors account for almost 80 per cent of the decline in multifactor productivity growth between the 1998/99 to 2003/04 and 2003/04 to 2007/08 growth cycles, a conclusion endorsed (at least initially) by the Australian Treasury (2009, pp 51–52). More recently, Treasury has retreated somewhat from this view: see, for example, Australian Government (2011, p 4–30) and Parkinson (2011, p 21).

There's no denying that both labour and multifactor productivity have fallen sharply in the mining and utilities sectors over the past decade.

The mining sector has been gearing up for a huge expansion in response to the demand for energy and minerals (particularly those associated with steelmaking) from China and India. To this end, hours worked in mining have more than doubled over the past decade, while the real value of the sector's productive capital stock has increased by almost 80 per cent. Yet, largely reflecting the long lead times entailed in bringing modern mining projects to full production, the output (gross valued added) of the mining sector has risen by only 37 per cent over this period (see Figure 4). As a result, the level of labour productivity has declined at an average annual rate of 6.2 per cent since 2001/02 (or by 41 per cent in total); while the level of multifactor productivity has fallen at an average annual rate of 4.5 per cent since peaking in 2000/01 (or by 34 per cent in total). Once these projects reach full production, measured labour and multifactor productivity should rebound strongly, potentially reversing much of their decline over the past decade.

Figure 4: Mining Sector Productivity

Another, possibly less transitory, drag on measured mining industry productivity arises from the fact that historically high prices for many metals have made it profitable to extract and refine low-grade deposits, which (by definition) require the application of more labour and capital in order to produce a given volume of ores or metals, and which would have remained untouched at lower prices.

This inevitably detracts from measured productivity, even though it represents logical and profitable business for mining companies. This drag will persist for as long as metal prices remain high by historical standards. Indeed, Mudd (2009) argues that ore grades will continue declining indefinitely, and the amount of ‘overburden’ required to be removed in order to gain access, especially to coal and base metals, will continue to increase over time.

A different set of factors have resulted in similar trends in productivity in the utilities sector. This was a sector which recorded substantial productivity gains in the 1990s, largely as a result of reforms engineered by state governments. During the past decade, however, electricity and gas businesses have had to invest heavily in response to continued growth in demand (especially for peak load, which inevitably entails a large degree of ‘redundancy’ at non-peak times), to replace ageing transmission infrastructure, and to meet government-mandated renewable energy targets. Likewise, governments have undertaken significant investments in water infrastructure (including desalination plants in five states), with a view to guaranteeing security of supply in drought conditions, while simultaneously imposing restrictions on the use of water throughout much of the decade, which detracted from the output of water businesses without commensurate reductions in factor inputs.

Thus, in this sector, hours worked have increased by 73 per cent over the past decade, and the real value of the productive capital stock by 35 per cent, whereas output has risen by only 15 per cent. Correspondingly, labour productivity has fallen by 34 per cent (an average annual rate of decline of 4.0 per cent) and multifactor productivity by 31 per cent (3.6 per cent per annum) (see Figure 5).

Figure 5: Utilities Sector Productivity

The output of the agriculture sector has obviously been affected by drought during the past decade, but it's not obvious that agricultural sector productivity has detracted from Australia's overall productivity performance over the past decade (see Figure 6). On the contrary, partly as a result of substantial labour-shedding in the early years of the decade, agricultural sector productivity rose at an average annual rate of 3.9 per cent over the 2000s, the second-fastest of any of the 16 industries making up the market sector, while multifactor productivity in agriculture rose at an average annual rate of 1.9 per cent, a more rapid rate than any other sector.

Figure 6: Agricultural, Forestry & Fishing Sector 
Productivity

The mining and utilities sectors together have, over the past decade, employed about 19 per cent of Australia's non-housing capital stock and a little over 2 per cent of Australia's workforce, to produce about 11 per cent of Australia's overall output. On that basis alone, it seems prima facie implausible that these two sectors could have accounted for nearly all of the decline in Australia's productivity since the turn of the century.

However, this is not something which can be verified by direct reference to the measures of productivity published by the ABS, since these are, consistent with international practice, published in index number form, with both labour and multifactor productivity for each industry set to 100 in the base year of the national accounts. This provides the most accurate basis for estimating rates of productivity growth for each sector over time, especially when the numerator in the measure of productivity is derived from chain volume estimates of output. However, the use of index numbers precludes comparisons of the levels of productivity across different industries at any given point in time and the exclusion of particular sectors which are believed to be distorting economy- or market sector-wide productivity (in order to arrive at some measure excluding those sectors, analogous to exclusion-based measures of ‘core’ inflation or ‘underlying’ economic activity).

In order to circumvent this problem, Eslake and Walsh (2011) constructed ‘dollar-denominated’ estimates of labour productivity by industry sector. This required the derivation of estimates of actual hours worked by industry by multiplying the published figures for average weekly hours worked in each industry by those for employment in each industry, both of which are available for the middle month of each quarter. The resulting estimates were then averaged for each financial year, and multiplied by 52 to derive an estimate of annual hours worked in each industry.[5] These estimates of aggregate hours worked were then divided into the published estimates of gross value added (GVA) by industry to derive estimates of GVA per hour worked, or labour productivity.

These estimates are shown for 2009/10 in Figure 7 below, while Figure 8 shows the behaviour of the measure of GVA per hour worked for the economy as a whole with the corresponding ABS index measure.

Figure 7: Labour Productivity by Industry
Figure 8: Total Economy Labour Productivity

The ordering of sectors by output per hour worked accords, in most cases, with what one would expect intuitively – that is, sectors which are intensive in their use of capital and/or skilled labour (such as mining, financial services, rental & hiring, IT & telecommunications, and utilities) have higher-than-average output per hour worked; while sectors which are relatively intensive in their use of unskilled labour (such as retailing, or accommodation & food services) have well-below average output per hour worked. There are a few apparent anomalies, such as education & training, or health care & social assistance, although since output in these sectors is in part measured by reference to labour and capital input, these need to be interpreted more cautiously.

Figure 9 shows estimates of both the 12- and 16-industry measures of market sector productivity, calculated as GVA per hour worked, including and excluding the mining and utilities sectors.

Figure 9: Labour Productivity Growth Including and Excluding the Mining and Utilities Sectors

For the market sector (as presently defined by ABS) as a whole, labour productivity growth declined from a peak of 3.1 per cent per annum over the five years to 1999/2000 to 1.7 per cent per annum over the five years to 2009/10, a decline of 1.4 percentage points. Excluding the mining and utilities sectors, market sector labour productivity declined from 3.2 per cent per annum to 1.9 per cent per annum over the same interval, a decline of 1.3 percentage points. For the larger group of ‘selected sectors’, labour productivity growth declined from a peak of 3.0 per cent per annum over the five years to 2001/02 to 1.2 per cent over the five years to 2009/10, a decline of 1.8 percentage points. Excluding the mining and utilities sectors, labour productivity growth for this group declined from 3.2 per cent to 1.4 per cent over the same interval, a decline also of 1.8 percentage points.

This suggests that the decline in labour productivity in the mining and utilities sectors accounts for less than 10 per cent of the decline in overall market sector productivity growth over the past decade – a considerably smaller contribution than suggested by the Productivity Commission's analysis referred to earlier (Productivity Commission 2010).

Given the rough-and-ready nature of these estimates, not too much precision should be attributed to this numerical conclusion. However, it does nonetheless suggest that the slowdown in Australian productivity growth has been broad-based rather than being largely the result of peculiar outcomes in a handful of industries.

This conclusion is supported by the observation that both labour and multifactor productivity growth have slowed in all but three of the sixteen sectors for which the ABS produces index-based estimates between the 1990s and 2000s. Those three sectors – construction, administration & support services, and arts & recreation services – account for 9.6 per cent of GDP and 11.2 per cent of GVA in industry.

The deterioration in Australia's (labour) productivity performance during the 2000s appears to have been more broadly based than in other comparable countries. Comparisons of productivity performance among countries at the industry level are complicated not only by the same measurement issues that pertain to comparisons of aggregate productivity (including that of the appropriate exchange rate) but also by differences in industrial classification systems.

The most readily available database allowing such comparisons to be made is the Groningen Growth and Development Centre's EU KLEMS (2009) database. The latest version of this database contains data only up to 2007. As summarised in Table 2, the data show that labour productivity growth in Australia slowed between 1990–2000 and 2000–2007 in 11 of the 15 broad industry groups used in EU KLEMS, compared with 7 in the United States, 9 in the euro area, 10 in the United Kingdom, 8 in Japan (for which the data is available only up to 2006), and 8 in Korea. Most other economies also experienced large declines in labour productivity growth in their mining and utilities sectors (almost as large in the United Kingdom as in Australia); but by comparison with the other economies shown in Table 2, Australia experienced particularly large declines in productivity growth in the wholesale & retail trade, transport & storage, financial services, public administration & defence, and education sectors.

The Productivity Commission (2011) has recently fleshed out this relatively poor performance in the context of the retail sector, producing estimates suggesting that labour productivity in that sector in 2007 was some 38 per cent lower than in the United States, some 20–35 per cent below that in France, Germany and the United Kingdom, and only marginally higher than in Greece or Spain. The estimates also suggest that both labour and multifactor productivity growth in retailing had been significantly slower in Australia than in the United States.

The Commission concluded that ‘it appears likely that the size of the gap between Australia and the US has been increasing; nor has Australia made any significant gains in its position in regards to other leading countries’ (Productivity Commission 2011, p 67). Similarly, Daley and Walsh (2011) have argued that labour productivity in the Australian construction sector declined by half relative to its US counterpart between 1990 and 2005.

So, as Stevens (2011) observed recently, ‘it is now just about impossible to avoid the conclusion that productivity growth performance has been quite poor since at least the mid 2000s’.

3.2 Other possibilities

If the deterioration in Australia's productivity performance isn't primarily explained by sharp falls in productivity in a small number of sectors of the Australian economy, then what else could explain it?

It seems eminently plausible that at least part of the slowdown in productivity growth is attributable to the fading of the impact of the reforms which are widely agreed to have been a substantial driver of the acceleration in productivity growth during the 1990s. This was reaffirmed recently by the Productivity Commission, which stated that ‘the reforms of the latter part of the 1980s and the 1990s’ were the ‘prime candidate’ for the most ‘likely causes of the surge in productivity’ during the 1990s (Productivity Commission 2010, p 62), and the OECD (2010a, p 14), as well as (as noted earlier) by Bean (2000) and Forsyth (2000) at the RBA Conference a decade ago.[6]

To the extent that the reforms of the 1980s and 1990s prompted ‘step changes’ in the level of productivity – as may well have been the case with, for example, the privatisation of government monopolies or with at least some aspects of ‘competition policy’ – then the fading of what appeared at the time to have been an increase in the rate of productivity growth is unsurprising.

Indeed, this was precisely what Bean (2000, pp 98–99) suggested would turn out to be the case, predicting that ‘most of the structural reforms should primarily have a once-off level effect, although it may take some years to work through fully’. At the same conference, Quiggin (2000, pp 269–270) suggested that much of the apparent increase in measured productivity growth during the 1990s could be explained by measured (or unmeasured) increases in working hours and by increases in ‘work intensity’. To the extent that either of these suggestions are accurate (and they were contested by other participants at the conference – see Gruen and Shesthra (2000, pp 275–276)), the increases in recorded productivity growth rates for which they accounted would also have been unsustainable.

It also seems highly plausible that at least part of the slowdown in productivity growth since the turn of the century is attributable to the absence of any significant productivity-enhancing reforms since that time (and that is, perhaps charitably, counting the reforms to the taxation system of 1999 and 2000 as ‘productivity enhancing’). As Garnaut has observed:

There has been no successful major step in productivity-raising reform since the tax changes associated with the introduction of the GST in 2001 … Economic policy since the GST has been characterised by change rather than productivity-raising reform. The use of independent analysis and transparent discussion of policy reform has become rare … [A]ttempts at major reform that had the potential to raise productivity and incomes, but failed comprehensively … poisoned the soil for further reform for a considerable while.

(Garnaut 2010, pp 7–8)

In particular, the workplace relations reforms introduced by the Howard Government under the title Work Choices in its last term in office were not, primarily, ‘productivity enhancing’. With the exception of the changes to ‘unfair dismissals’ procedures, they did not entail a significant degree of further labour market deregulation, but rather provided for a change in the level of government responsible for the regulation of the labour market, and to some extent in the purposes for which that regulation was pursued. To the extent that it had succeeded in one of its stated objectives of increasing the participation in employment of people with limited skills, it would have (at least initially) detracted from measured labour productivity (although that would not, by itself, be a reason for objecting to the elements of Work Choices intended to bring about that result).[7]

The dearth of productivity-enhancing reforms since about 2000 is clearly in part attributable to changes in the political environment, including a diminution in the enthusiasm of both major political parties for continuing reforms of the type pursed in the 1980s and early 1990s once the politically ‘easiest’ reforms (what management consultants typically call the ‘low-hanging fruit’) had been accomplished, and once what remained was seen as more politically ‘challenging’, including to important elements of the ‘core constituencies’ of both sides of Australian politics.[8] Changes in voting behaviour – particularly in rural and regional areas, but also in areas such as western Sydney – made both major political parties more sensitive to the views of those who perceived themselves (not always inaccurately) as ‘losers’ from the reforms of the 1980s and 1990s.

The lack of enthusiasm for productivity-enhancing reforms since about 2000, on the part of both political leaders and the public at large, also seems in part attributable, paradoxically, to the generally more prosperous economic circumstances of the last decade.

The reforms of the 1980s and 1990s were to a significant degree prompted by the economic vulnerabilities exposed by the persistence of high inflation and unemployment since the mid 1970s, the decline in Australia's terms of trade during the 1970s and 1980s, and two severe recessions occurring within less than a decade, which prompted the then leaders of both sides of Australian politics to ‘embrace … the free market agenda and its gradual application as the solution to Australia's underlying problems’ (Kelly 1992, p 660), and an at least tacit, if not wholehearted, acceptance of that agenda on the part of the Australian electorate at large.

By contrast, the past decade has been one of almost uninterrupted growth in economic activity, employment and household disposable income, lower unemployment than at any time since the mid 1970s, sound public finances (especially by comparison with other advanced economies), relatively low and stable inflation, relatively low and stable interest rates, a generally rising exchange rate (something widely seen among the broader population as a short-hand summary of international investors' views of Australia's economic performance) and (perhaps most importantly in this context) a dramatic reversal of the downward trend in Australia's terms of trade which had prevailed throughout most of the 20th century.

Garnaut (2005, p 3) speaks of ‘a Great Complacency that descended upon the country after a decade of exceptional economic growth … As a community, we accepted the excellent economic performance as evidence that we had changed enough’. More recently, Stevens (2011) has noted that ‘past periods of apparently easy affluence, conferred by favourable international conditions, probably lessened the sharpness of our focus on productivity’.

This ‘diminished focus’ on productivity over the past decade has not been confined to the public policy arena. As the profit share of Australia's national income has increased to unprecedented levels during the past decade (apart from the period immediately after the global financial crisis), businesses have in general attached less importance to the pursuit of productivity gains at the enterprise or workplace level (which is, after all, where the decisions that actually lead to higher levels of productivity are formulated and executed, if at all). A survey conducted by Telstra (2010) found that, among over 300 organisations each with over 200 employees:

  • only 42 per cent measure their productivity, have specific productivity targets and know what they are, while 25 per cent don't measure their productivity at all;
  • only 22 per cent believe that they can accurately measure productivity benefits when considering investment decisions; and
  • only 34 per cent of firms assign individual responsibilities for productivity improvements.

As with the diminished enthusiasm for productivity-enhancing reforms at the political level, this low emphasis on the measurement of, and accountability for, productivity at the enterprise level is to at least some extent understandable. Productivity-enhancing change in individual workplaces is often disruptive and unpleasant; both for those on the ‘receiving end’ of that change and those (typically ‘middle managers’) who have to communicate it to those affected and implement it. When making such changes is no longer a matter of survival – as it was for many businesses in the 1990s – it is not surprising that the appetite for making them has diminished.

It is also to some extent inevitable, and consistent with both historical experience and the contemporary experience of other countries, that as the Australian economy moved closer to ‘full capacity’ in the second half of the 2000s, a situation characterised by (among other things) increasing shortages of skilled labour and the emergence of ‘bottlenecks’ in key areas of infrastructure provision, measured productivity would deteriorate – irrespective of whether political and business leaders had maintained their earlier enthusiasm for productivity-enhancing change in either public policy-making or business decision-making.

Another important and, in this context, pertinent development of the past decade has been the increasing volume of legislation and regulation in reaction to corporate scandals, various actual or perceived threats to ‘security’, and other more quotidian aspects of life.

A common belief underpinning this legislation and regulation appears to be that it is both possible and desirable to eliminate various kinds of risk (to life, to property, to public order and safety, to people's savings, to standards of corporate or private behaviour, and so on) through additional legislative or regulatory action, irrespective of the probabilities attached to those risks, irrespective of the adequacy of already existing legislation or regulation to that end, and irrespective of the costs of seeking to eliminate those risks relative to the benefits of doing so.[9]

Much of this legislation and regulation has required the employment of additional staff, the acquisition of additional capital equipment or the costly modification of existing buildings and infrastructure, without resulting in the production of any additional (measured) goods or services, and often with the incidental effect of diverting the time and attention of other people from activities that would have otherwise resulted in the production of additional goods and services.

In other words, whatever public or private benefits that have been procured through legislation and regulation of this type have inevitably come at some cost in terms of productivity.

Of course, such costs may well be seen by many as an example of where, in Krugman's famous aphorism, ‘productivity isn't everything’: but that is not to deny that such costs have been real.

Nor has Australia's experience in this regard been unique, although when one looks beyond the realm of aviation security to other aspects of business and personal life, the quantum and reach of ‘risk-averting’ legislation and regulation may well have been more pervasive in Australia than in many other advanced economies.

Although difficult to verify in any empirical manner, there is considerable anecdotal evidence suggesting that the increased recourse to legislative and regulatory means of eliminating various types of risks has prompted business owners and managers to devote increasing proportions of their time and attention to compliance and risk management activities, and to have become less willing to take on some of the risks inevitably associated with decisions to undertake organisational change, enter new markets, develop new products or services, or engage in other forms of productivity-enhancing innovation.

One illustration of this may be the apparent decline in Australia's relative take-up of new technologies. In the second half of the 1990s, Australia typically ranked behind only the Nordic countries and the United States in various (objective and subjective) measures of the penetration or diffusion of new information and communications technologies. By the end of the past decade, however, Australia's ranking had slipped to, typically, between 15th and 22nd, behind not only the United States and Nordic countries but also a large number of Western European countries, a growing number of Asian economies, Canada and Israel (see Table 3).

Although some dimensions of Australia's innovation effort – for example, gross expenditure on research and development (R&D) as a percentage of GDP – have improved over the past decade, in many others Australia still falls well short of OECD ‘best practice’:

  • only 2.4 per cent of Australian firms introduced one or more product innovations that were new to international markets in 2008/09, compared with 10 per cent of Japanese firms, between 20–35 per cent of European firms, and even 20 per cent of New Zealand firms;
  • only 9.6 per cent of Australian firms introduced one or more product innovations that were new to their domestic market in 2008/09, a slightly better figure than that for German firms of 7.4 per cent, but below the 10–15 per cent figures common for firms from other European economies, 25.3 per cent for Japanese firms, and even 15.4 per cent for New Zealand firms; and
  • by contrast, Australian firms are much more likely to modify or adopt products or processes that already exist in domestic markets, which ‘might contribute to specialisation of existing markets [but] it will not necessarily create or confer any “first mover” competitive advantage’ (DIISR 2011, p 26).

Australian business investment in intangibles is also relatively low by OECD standards, at 5.9 per cent of GDP in 2006, lower than all but three of the sixteen countries (Italy, Slovakia and Spain) for which these data were available, and substantially below the United States (12.0 per cent), Japan (11.1 per cent), Canada (9.8 per cent) and the UK (9.7 per cent) (OECD 2010a).

Although Australia's relatively low ranking on these comparisons may be partly a function of the structure of its economy (with a relatively small manufacturing sector, and relatively high levels of foreign ownership in R&D-intensive sectors such as pharmaceuticals) or its scale and distance from other major markets, the comparisons with Canada (whose economic structure is in many ways similar to Australia's) and New Zealand (which is considerably smaller, and more remote, than Australia) caution against these being the sole explanations.

It would be wrong to suggest that there is any single, or overwhelming, ‘cause’ of Australia's poor productivity performance over the past decade. But there seems to be little doubt that the broader economic and political environment (one in which there has been little pressure on either policy-makers or individual firms to pursue productivity-enhancing structural or organisational change) has been of critical importance. As Parkinson (2011, p 22) put it, ‘the root causes of Australia's present productivity performance are embedded in the decisions of the last decade’.

4. Consequences of the Deterioration in Australia's Productivity Performance

As noted earlier, the connections between productivity growth and improvements in (material) living standards have been long established in the economics literature. Yet it is not immediately apparent that the deterioration in Australia's productivity performance during the 2000s has as yet had serious consequences for the living standards of Australian citizens. Real household disposable income rose at a 4.1 per cent average annual rate over the decade ended 2009/10, compared with 2.5 per cent per annum during the 1990s, 2.3 per cent per annum during the 1980s and 2.1 per cent per annum during the 1970s, while real household net worth rose at a 5.8 per cent annual rate over the ten years to June 2010 (notwithstanding the losses suffered during the global financial crisis) compared with 5.1 per cent per annum over the preceding decade. Reflecting this, real household consumption spending rose at a 3.4 per cent average annual rate during the 2000s, slightly above the 3.3 per cent annual rate during the 1990s.

The apparent contradiction between falling productivity growth rates and rising material living standards can be explained by noting that, during the 2000s, the consequences of Australia's declining productivity growth rate were offset (for most of the decade) by a rising population growth rate and (insofar as gross domestic income (GDI) rather than GDP is used as a measure of national income) by the surge in Australia's terms of trade to their highest sustained level in at least 140 years.

As shown in Figure 10, growth in real GDI averaged 4.0 per cent per annum over the decade to 2009/10, compared with 3.2 per cent per annum over the previous decade. Of the former figure, labour productivity growth contributed 1.4 percentage points, down from 2.1 percentage points in the 1990s. Declining average labour force participation subtracted 0.1 percentage points from real GDI growth in both decades, while population growth contributed 1.8 percentage points to the average annual rate of real GDI in the 2000s, 0.4 percentage points more than during the 1990s. The terms of trade gains boosted real GDI growth by an average of 0.9 percentage points per annum during the 2000s, in contrast to the 0.1 percentage point detraction from real GDI growth on average during the 1990s which resulted from a deterioration in Australia's terms of trade.

Figure 10: Real Gross Domestic Income

There is a very strong echo here of Australia's experience during the 1950s, 1960s and early 1970s.

Then, as during the past decade, the consequences of a rather ordinary (by international standards) productivity performance were obscured by the combination of rapid population growth (the result, in turn, of the post-war baby boom common throughout the world, and Australia's own post-war immigration program) and the benefits to Australia (both through terms of trade gains and increases in production capacity) arising from the urbanisation and industrialisation of what during this period became our largest export market (namely, Japan). But when the post-war population boom came to an end (in the early 1970s) – and shortly afterwards Japan more or less ‘caught up’ with US and Western European levels of per capita GDP and the commodity intensity of its economy subsequently began to decline – the consequences of Australia's poor productivity performance for Australians' living standards became more readily apparent in the form of weaker average economic growth rates, and persistently high inflation and unemployment.

The same fate could await Australia in the decade ahead now that population growth has begun to slow, as demographic change erodes labour force participation rates and average hours worked, and if, as both Treasury and Reserve Bank forecasts presume, Australia's terms of trade have reached their peak.

Indeed, Parkinson (2011, p 15) argues that ‘the rate of improvement in the living standards of Australians, at least that part measured by incomes, has already begun to deteriorate, even with the sustained and unprecedented rise in the terms of trade’.

Another important consequence of Australia's persistently poor productivity performance is a greater propensity to inflation, even under outcomes for wage growth that would not, historically, have been regarded as ominous from that perspective. As shown in Figure 11, the combination of growth in average compensation per non-farm employee of more than 5½ per cent over the year to the March quarter 2011 (a figure which is high by the standards of the past two decades but by no means unprecedented) with a fall in labour productivity of 1¾ per cent over the same period has resulted in unit labour cost growth of almost 8½ per cent, the fastest since the late 1980s.

Figure 11: Employee Compensation, Labour Productivity and Unit Labour Costs

Given the role played by unit labour costs in most contemporary models of the inflationary process,[10] this is a clear warning sign of upward risks to inflation emanating from this source despite the continued moderation (by historical standards) evident in other measures of wage growth.

5. What (If Anything) Is To Be Done?

Keynes (1919, p 220) attributed to Lenin the assertion that ‘the best way to destroy the Capitalist System was to debauch the currency’, although there is no evidence that Lenin actually did say this. Lenin did, however, ask ‘What is to be done?’ in a pamphlet written to explain ‘the difference between the amateurish methods which satisfy the Economists, and the organisation of revolutionaries which we hold to be indispensable’ (Lenin 1961, preface).

Without in any way endorsing his methods, Lenin's question seems an appropriate one with which to conclude this discussion of Australia's productivity performance over the past decade. What is to be done about Australia's deteriorating productivity performance?

It's by no means inconceivable that the answer to this question could be ‘nothing’. Indeed, historical precedent strongly suggests that Australians, and their political representatives, will feel no great compulsion to embrace a program of productivity-enhancing economic reforms for as long as the mining boom – and the various channels through which the income generated by that boom is recycled and redistributed throughout the Australian economy – delivers continued growth in incomes and high levels of employment.

It is also possible that the difficulties now being encountered by sectors of the economy which are adversely affected by some of the side-effects of the mining boom, in particular the rising exchange rate (something which did not occur to the same extent, if at all, during previous commodities booms) will prompt businesses in those sectors, of their own volition, to place a much higher priority on productivity-enhancing organisational and other changes at the enterprise or workplace levels, as a matter of survival, without any need for public policy changes.

But if Australian policy-makers were to decide to seek public policy solutions to the problems posed now or for the future by Australia's deteriorating productivity performance, what might those look like?

At the outset, it is important to keep in mind that productivity improvements occur as the result of decisions taken by and implemented in enterprises and workplaces, not as the direct result of public policy initiatives.

Public policy initiatives can contribute to improving Australia's productivity performance to the extent that they:

  • increase the incentives facing the owners or managers of enterprises (including government agencies themselves) to make productivity-enhancing changes (to the goods and services they produce, or the way in which they are produced);
  • increase the ability of owners or managers of enterprises to implement productivity-enhancing changes once they have decided to make them (or, alternatively, reducing the barriers and obstacles to implementing productivity-enhancing change); or
  • facilitate the movement of factors of production from existing uses to ones in which they can be combined in ways that result in higher levels of productivity overall.

As Parkinson has commented, ‘[w]e do ourselves, and the nation, a disservice if we target reform efforts only on the same areas as we have in the past’ (Parkinson 2011, p 24). Many of those past reforms were, intrinsically, once-off in their nature: tariffs, once reduced to minimal levels, can't be cut again; government monopolies, once privatised, can't be privatised again (unless they've been renationalised in the meantime); and markets, once deregulated, can't be deregulated again (unless the deregulation has been only partial, and there's a good case for going further).

5.1 Regulatory reform

However, there are many areas of the Australian economy that have, mainly for political reasons, remained largely insulated from competitive pressures of the sort that, in other sectors, have acted as strong incentives for the pursuit of productivity-enhancing structural and organisational change. These include, international aviation, agricultural marketing (other than grains), pharmacies, newsagents, private sector service professions (such as law, medicine and architecture), and services sectors dominated by public sector agencies (such as health and aged care, education, public transport and law enforcement).

Some of these are, admittedly, relatively small as a share of output or employment, while others (in particular the service delivery sectors just mentioned) are both large themselves, and important ‘enablers’ for other sectors of the economy. One of the key obstacles to the pursuit of productivity-enhancing reforms in these areas is the widespread (and bipartisan) belief that there is a linear correlation between the number of people employed in delivering these services and the quality of them, notwithstanding the absence of any empirical evidence in support of that belief (for example, between staff-student ratios in schools and student outcomes, or between police numbers and crime rates).

Banks (2010, p 15) has suggested that ‘the productivity enhancing reforms that deserve some priority right now are those that can reduce business costs and enhance the economy's supply-side responsiveness, while being fiscally parsimonious’. Specifically:

  • reducing any government assistance to industry ‘not justified by genuine market failures’;
  • government procurement, including defence procurement favouring high-cost local production without any obvious social benefit;
  • projects that do not demonstrably yield a social benefit;
  • human services programs where benchmark data suggest scope for more cost-effective delivery (in particular health services); and
  • regulatory constraints on adaptability and flexibility at the enterprise level, particularly those impacting on the markets for labour and capital, and key infrastructural inputs such as transport, energy, telecommunications and water.

Banks lays particular emphasis on industrial relations and the labour market, pointing out that:

Whether productivity growth comes from working harder or working ‘smarter’, people in workplaces are central to it. The incentives they face and how well their skills are deployed and redeployed in the multitude of enterprises that make up our economy underpins its aggregate performance. It is therefore vital to ensure that regulations intended to promote fairness in Australia's workplaces do not detract unduly from their productivity … If we are to secure Australia's productivity potential into the future, the regulation of labour markets cannot remain a no-go area for evidence-based policy making.

(Banks 2010, p 16)

The Productivity Commission's recent draft report on retailing noted that closing the productivity gap between Australia and countries such as the United States ‘will require greater workplace flexibility so that employers and employees can work cooperatively and creatively together, to deliver the required productivity improvements’ (Productivity Commission 2011, p 287). The report also suggested that ‘some aspects of the [Fair Work] system may be inhibiting the adoption of flexibility enhancing provisions’ in retailing workplace arrangements (pp 306–307), and observed that the workplace flexibility provisions in the ‘Fair Work’ system appear to have been used to place ‘greater emphasis on strategies for developing family-friendly workplaces, rather than productivity’ (p 319).

Of course, the scope for regulatory reform extends well beyond the workplace relations framework. The OECD's recent review of Australian regulatory practices describes Australia as ‘one of the front-running countries in the OECD in terms of its regulatory reform practices’ (OECD 2010c, p 16) and observes that ‘[i]n general the Australian States demonstrate regulatory management practices that are among OECD best practice’ (p 17).

Nonetheless, the Business Council of Australia (BCA) argues that ‘significant reforms … are needed in all jurisdictions to improve their regulatory process’ (BCA 2010, p 9), and the OECD itself notes in a separate publication the need for further reforms in infrastructure regulation, and also that Australia's barriers to foreign direct investment are the seventh highest in the OECD (OECD 2010b, pp 99 and 47). Policy-makers and regulators have continued to respond to new social or economic issues with ‘knee-jerk regulatory solutions’, as the Regulation Taskforce (2006, p 148) reported to the Howard Government. Hence, as the BCA urges, ‘[t]here needs to be a comprehensive model that incorporates both prospective and retrospective reforms to prevent bad regulation from being made in the first place’ (BCA 2010, p 4).

There are also still examples where outright deregulation ought to be more actively considered. For example, Abelson (2010, p 41) demonstrates that the removal of restrictions governing entry into the Sydney taxi industry (for which there are ‘few efficiency or social reasons’) could produce benefits ‘in the order of $265 million per annum’, with even greater productivity and service benefits if accompanied by reform of the ‘anti-competitive control of the taxi radio networks over all taxi operators’. Similarly, the Productivity Commission (2011, pp 269–284) has recently highlighted the potential benefits of the removal of remaining restrictions on retail trading hours.

5.2 Taxation reform

Tax reform could play an important role in improving Australia's productivity performance. Australia's personal and business income tax systems (and state land and payroll tax systems) are littered with exemptions and concessions which confer favourable treatment on particular groups of taxpayers, particular forms of business organisation, or particular types of economic activity at the expense of others, leading to household and business investment decisions often being excessively influenced by tax considerations rather than their intrinsic merit (which must be to the detriment of productivity, among other things).

The Henry Review of Australia's tax system urged that ‘Australia should configure its tax and transfer architecture to promote stronger economic growth through participation and productivity’ (Australia's Future Tax System Review Panel 2009, p xviii). Unfortunately, many of the Review's recommendations to that end were promptly ruled out – by both sides of politics – for transparently political reasons.

5.3 Skills and infrastructure

To the extent that Australia's poor productivity performance over the past decade reflects past under-investment, or poorly targeted investment, in skills formation and in infrastructure, some combination of more and better targeted investment in these areas will contribute to improved productivity performance, albeit with lags that are inevitably protracted. These two areas have been key elements of the current Australian Government's ‘broad ranging and extensive productivity agenda’ (Australian Government 2011, p 4–32).

Yet despite the continuing upward trend in the proportion of the Australian working-age population with formal educational qualifications, it is not at all clear that the quality of Australian human capital has increased significantly.

The OECD concluded, earlier in the decade, that ‘skill upgrading has played, at best, a modest role in GDP growth per employed person’ in Australia (and also in Canada, the Netherlands, New Zealand and the United States) (OECD 2003, p 37). An ABS survey undertaken as part of an OECD study of adult literacy and life skills found that 46 per cent of Australians aged 15–74 lacked the minimum prose and document literacy skills, 50 per cent lacked the minimum numeracy skills, and 70 per cent lacked the problem-solving skills ‘required for individuals to meet the complex demands of everyday life and work in the emerging knowledge-based economy’ (ABS 2008a, p 5).

It has been recognised for some time that younger Australians from lower socio-economic backgrounds tend to lag at least one year behind the Australian average, and more than two years behind students in the highest socio-economic quartile (OECD 2010b, p 139). The results from the latest OECD Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA) suggest that the performance of Australian 15-year-old students has declined significantly over the past decade, despite a 33 per cent real increase in public expenditure, and a 54 per cent real increase in private expenditure, on education during this period (Jensen 2010).

By comparison with schools and higher education, the vocational education and training (VET) sector attracts little public attention. Yet there is evidence that the effectiveness of the training provided by this sector is variable, and that this sector is characterised by low completion rates in occupations that regularly appear on national skills shortages lists (Australian Government 2008, p 4–20).

It is widely accepted that Australia's infrastructure, particularly in transport, is inadequate for many of the requirements of Australia's growing economic, personal and social needs, and that this is in part due to under-investment in infrastructure in the 1980s and 1990s. However, as the OECD notes, it also reflects ‘weak co-ordination between public infrastructure development and fiscal management’ and a ‘lack of co-ordination between the various levels of government, and between jurisdictions at the same level’, so that ‘[i]nfrastructure spending decisions are frequently taken with no regard for national priorities’ (OECD 2010c, p 95).

The solution to these weaknesses is not simply more spending on infrastructure, especially if that spending is as unco-ordinated and with as little regard for national priorities as in the past. It is of no less importance to the objectives of higher levels of productivity or faster productivity growth that better use is made of existing infrastructure, including through rational pricing regimes, and through avoiding ill-conceived regulation that detracts from the efficiency with which existing infrastructure is used (for example, by arbitrary and knee-jerk reductions in speed limits on roads, or ‘security’ procedures entailing excessive or unnecessary delays in the movement of goods and passengers through airports).

5.4 Innovation

It is widely accepted, and not just by economists, that ‘[i]nnovation can increase productivity through the creation of higher value products, more efficient production processes, more effective workplace organisation and opening up new markets’ (DIISR 2011, p 8). The fact that, as noted earlier, Australia's innovation effort falls well short of OECD ‘best practice’ on many dimensions, thus suggests the potential for improvements in Australia's innovation effort to contribute to higher levels of productivity and faster rates of productivity growth.

In this area, no less than in any others, it is important to emphasise that productivity growth happens as a result of decisions being taken and implemented by the owners and managers of individual enterprises (and government agencies), and that the role of public policy is to improve the incentives facing those owners and managers to undertake productivity-enhancing innovations, and to remove obstacles to the undertaking of such innovations where they have been inadvertently created by past public policy interventions.

This is not simply a matter of more generous tax concessions for business R&D expenditures, or higher levels of public expenditure on R&D. As Dodgson et al argue, ‘[m]odern innovation policy has to recognise, explicitly, that market mechanisms can be used effectively … as devices that permit flexibility, selection and change in a complex-evolutionary economic system’ (Dodgson et al 2009, p 33).

Among the issues that could be usefully considered in this domain are:

  • the extent to which Australia's competition laws inhibit the kind of collaboration among firms in the same industry which overseas experience suggests is an integral part of the innovation process in many industries;
  • the extent to which the treatment of options by the Australian taxation system inhibits the ability of ‘start-up’ companies to attract and retain talented staff, or to attract institutional investment; and
  • the extent to which what appears to be a highly legalistic approach on the part of many Australian universities to intellectual property rights inhibits the transfer of knowledge between those undertaking ‘pure’ or ‘basic’ research in higher education institutions to innovative entrepreneurs.

6. Conclusion

Although Australia's economic performance during the 2000s has been impressive on many dimensions, especially by comparison with that of other advanced economies, productivity is not among them. Australia's productivity performance over the past decade has been, to put it mildly, poor – both by Australia's own historical standards, and by contemporary international standards.

The consequences of this poor productivity performance have not, as yet, become widely apparent, because they have been masked by a combination of faster population growth (until recently) and the most sustained upswing in Australia's terms of trade in over a century.

Together with a weakening of an earlier, widely shared consensus around the need for ongoing economic reform that is perhaps the inevitable result of what has now been the longest period of more-or-less uninterrupted economic growth in more than a century, accompanied by falling unemployment, rising real incomes (which have in turn been fairly widely distributed), and rising personal wealth (for most of the past two decades), the sense that sustaining high rates of productivity growth is an important objective both for Australia as a whole and for individual businesses has declined substantially.

It may well be that an end to this period of comparatively easy prosperity – at least for sectors of the Australian economy that are adversely affected by some of the side-effects of the mining boom, or by the more frugal behaviour of Australian households, and possibly for the broader Australian economy if the global economy enters a renewed downturn with limited means on the part of economic policy-makers in the major advanced economies to ameliorate using the tools that have become customary over the past 70 years – will prompt a renewed focus, both among policy-makers and business leaders, on the objective of raising both the level of productivity and the rate of productivity growth.

If not, then it is unlikely that retrospective evaluations of the performance of the Australian economy over the 2010s, or the 2020s, will be as flattering as those of the past two decades.

Footnotes

Chief Economist at Bank of America Merrill Lynch, Australia. At the time of the Conference, Saul Eslake was Director, Productivity Growth Program – The Grattan Institute and Advisor, Economics & Policy, PricewaterhouseCoopers Australia. [*]

Some of Smith's less admirable notions about the relative productivity of the manufacturing and services sectors continue to influence policy-makers' thinking today: ‘[T]he labour of a manufacturer adds, generally, to the value of the materials which he works upon, that of his own maintenance, and of his master's profit. The labour of a menial servant, on the contrary, adds to the value of nothing’ (Smith 1937, Book II, p 314); compare ‘I don't want to be Prime Minister of a country which doesn't make things any more’ (Rudd (2007), emphasis added). [1]

The latest series of ABS estimates of multifactor productivity (ABS 2010a) goes back only to 1994/95. Hence, the rates of multifactor productivity growth cited for the 1990s, 1980s and 1970s have been derived from ABS (2008b, Table 13). [2]

On the grounds that the United States has higher GDP per hour worked than any other OECD country except for Luxembourg and Norway, two small economies each with an unusually large proportion of the economy accounted for by a sector with intrinsically high levels of labour productivity, namely financial services and oil extraction, respectively. [3]

An illustration, perhaps, of the first part of Krugman's widely quoted aphorism that ‘[p]roductivity isn't everything, [even if] in the long run it's almost everything’ (Krugman 1992, p 9). [4]

To the extent that the hours worked in the survey week of the middle month of each quarter are unrepresentative of that quarter as a whole, the resulting estimates of total hours worked may be inaccurate. In practice, however, the behaviour through time of the resulting productivity estimates does not appear to be significantly different from that of the corresponding ABS index numbers. [5]

Salgado (2000) is another useful study in this context. [6]

For more on this point, see Eslake (2006). [7]

For example, newsagents, pharmacies, farming interests and the traditional professions (for the Liberal and National Parties), and public sector unions (for the Labor Party). [8]

See, for example, Mueller and Stewart (2011) for a cost-benefit analysis of the aviation security measures adopted in the United States (and to a very large extent emulated in Australia) after the terrorist attacks on New York and Washington on 11 September, 2001, and subsequent actual or attempted terrorist incidents around the world. [9]

See, for example, Norman and Richards (2010). [10]

References

Abelson P (2010), ‘The High Cost of Taxi Regulation, with Special Reference to Sydney’, Agenda, 17(2), pp 41–70.

ABS (Australian Bureau of Statistics) (2008a), Adult Literacy and Life Skills Survey, Summary Results, Australia, 2006 (Reissue), ABS Cat No 4228.0.

ABS (2008b), Australian System of National Accounts, 2007-08, ABS Cat No 5204.0.

ABS (2010a), Australian System of National Accounts, 2009-10, ABS Cat No 5204.0.

ABS (2010b), ‘Experimental Estimates of Industry Multifactor Productivity, 2009–10’, ABS Cat No 5260.0.55.002.

ABS (2011a), ‘Australian National Accounts: National Income, Expenditure and Product, Mar 2011’, ABS Cat No 5206.0.

ABS (2011b), ‘Labour Force, Australia, Detailed, Quarterly, May 2011’, ABS Cat No 6291.0.55.003.

Australian Government (2008), ‘Statement 4: Boosting Australia's Productive Capacity: The Role of Infrastructure and Skills’, in 2008–09 Australian Government Budget – Budget Paper No 1, Commonwealth of Australia, Canberra , pp 4–1–4–31.

Australian Government (2011), ‘Statement 4: Opportunities and Challenges of an Economy in Transition’, in 2011–12 Australian Government Budget – Budget Paper No 1, Commonwealth of Australia, Canberra, pp 4–1–4–39.

Australian Treasury (2009), ‘Raising the Level of Productivity Growth in the Australian Economy’, Economic Roundup, 3, pp 47–66.

Australia's Future Tax System Review Panel (2009), Australia's Future Tax System – Report to the Treasurer: Part One Overview, K Henry (chairperson), Commonwealth of Australia, Canberra.

Banks G (2010), ‘Successful Reform: Past Lessons, Future Challenges’, Address to the Annual Forecasting Conference of Australian Business Economists, Sydney, 8 December. Available at <http://www.pc.gov.au/speeches/successful-reform>.

BCA (Business Council of Australia) (2010), 2010 Scorecard of Red Tape Reform, Business Council of Australia, Melbourne.

Bean C (2000), ‘The Australian Economic ‘Miracle’: A View from the North’, in D Gruen and S Shrestha (eds), The Australian Economy in the 1990s, Proceedings of a Conference, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney, pp 74–114.

Conference Board, The (2011), ‘Total Economy DatabaseTM’, January. Available at <http://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/>.

Daley J and M Walsh (2011), ‘Losing the Productivity Race’, The Australian Financial Review, 7 July, p 63.

DIISR (Department of Innovation, Industry, Science and Research) (2011), Australian Innovation System Report 2011, Department of Innovation, Industry, Science and Research, Canberra.

Dodgson M, J Foster, A Hughes and JS Metcalfe (2009), ‘Systems Thinking, Market Failure, and the Development of Innovation Policy: The Case of Australia’, University of Cambridge, Centre for Business Research Working Paper No 397.

Eslake S (2006), ‘Demystifying Industrial Relations Reform’, The Melbourne Review, 2(1), pp 19–27.

Eslake S and M Walsh (2011), Australia's Productivity Challenge, Grattan Institute Report No 2011-1.

EU KLEMS (2009), ‘Growth and Productivity Accounts: November 2009 Release’, updated March 2011. Available at <http://www.euklems.net/>.

Forsyth P (2000), ‘Microeconomic Policies and Structural Change’, in D Gruen and S Shrestha (eds), The Australian Economy in the 1990s, Proceedings of a Conference, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney, pp 235–267.

Garnaut R (2005), ‘Breaking the Australian Great Complacency of the Early Twenty First Century’, Paper presented to the Melbourne Institute and The Australian Economic and Social Outlook Conference 2005 ‘Sustaining Prosperity: New Reform Opportunities for Australia’, Melbourne, 31 March–1 April. Available at <http://www.rossgarnaut.com.au/Documents/Breaking%20the%20Australian%20Complacency%20of%20the%2021st%20Century%202005.pdf>.

Garnaut R (2010), ‘Climate Change, China Booms and Australia's Governance Struggle in a Changing World’, 2010 Hamer Oration, Melbourne, 5 August.

Gruen D and S Shrestha (eds) (2000), The Australian Economy in the 1990s, Proceedings of a Conference, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney.

Jensen B (2010), ‘Future Compromised by Failures in Education System’, The Australian, 10 December, p 12.

Kelly P (1992), The End of Certainty: The Story of the 1990s, Allen & Unwin, St Leonards.

Keynes JM (1919), The Economic Consequences of the Peace, Macmillan, London.

Krugman P (1992), The Age of Diminished Expectations: U.S. Economic Policy in the 1980s, paperback edn, The MIT Press, Cambridge.

Lenin VI (1961), ‘What is to be Done? Burning Questions of our Movement’, in Collected Works, Volume 5, trans J Fineberg and G Hanna, Foreign Languages Publishing House, Moscow, pp 347–530.

Mudd GM (2009), The Sustainability of Mining in Australia: Key Production Trends and Their Environmental Implications for the Future, Monash University Department of Civil Engineering and Mineral Policy Institute Research Report No RR5.

Mueller J and MG Stewart (2011), ‘Terror, Security, and Money: Balancing the Risks, Benefits, and Costs of Homeland Security’, Paper presented at the MidWest Political Science Association 69th Annual National Conference, Chicago, 31 March–3 April.

Norman D and A Richards (2010), ‘Modelling Inflation in Australia’, RBA Research Discussion Paper No 2010-03.

OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2003), The Sources of Economic Growth in OECD Countries, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2010a), Measuring Innovation: A New Perspective, OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2010b), OECD Economic Surveys: Australia 2010, 2010(21), OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2010c), OECD Reviews of Regulatory Reform: Australia 2010 – Towards a Seamless National Economy, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Parkinson M (2011), ‘Sustaining Growth in Living Standards in the Asian Century’, Address to the Melbourne Institute and The Australian Economic and Social Outlook Conference 2011 ‘Growth Challenge: Riding the Resources Boom to Lasting Prosperity’, Melbourne, 30 June–1 July.

Productivity Commission (2010), Annual Report 2009-10, Annual Report Series, Productivity Commission, Canberra.

Productivity Commission (2011), Economic Structure and Performance of the Australian Retail Industry, Draft Report, Productivity Commission, Canberra.

Quiggin J (2000), ‘Discussion’, in D Gruen and S Shrestha (eds), The Australian Economy in the 1990s, Proceedings of a Conference, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney, pp 268–271.

Regulation Taskforce (2006), Rethinking Regulation: Report of the Taskforce on Reducing Regulatory Burdens on Business, Report to the Prime Minister and Treasurer, Canberra, January.

Rudd K (2007), ‘A Party for the Future’, Address to the National Conference of the Australian Labor Party, Sydney, 27 April.

Salgado R (2000), ‘Australia: Productivity Growth and Structural Reform’, in ‘Australia – Selected Issues and Statistical Appendix’, IMF Country Staff Report No 00/24, pp 3–35.

Sellar WC and RJ Yeatman (1930), 1066 and All That: A Memorable History of England Comprising All the Parts You Can Remember Including One Hundred and Three Good Things, Five Bad Kings, and Two Genuine Dates, Methuen, London.

Smith A (1937), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, copied from 5th edn, Random House, Inc., New York.

Stevens G (2009), ‘Challenges For Economic Policy’, Address to the Anika Foundation Luncheon supported by Australian Business Economists and Macquarie Bank, Sydney, 28 July.

Stevens G (2011), ‘The Cautious Consumer’, Address to the Anika Foundation Luncheon supported by Australian Business Economists and Macquarie Bank, Sydney, 26 July.

Telstra (2010), ‘The Telstra Productivity Indicator 2010’, A Report on Business Attitudes and Behaviours Towards Improving Productivity in Australia. Available at <http://www.telstraenterprise.com/SiteCollectionDocuments/Whitepapers/Productivity2010.pdf>.