RDP 9110: Resource Convergence and Intra-Industry Trade 3. Intra-Industry Trade

(a) Models

There are two principal sets of models of intra-industry trade, both resting on the assumption of imperfect competition. The first, developed by Brander and Krugman (1983) focusses on oligopolistic firms' incentives to price discriminate between countries. It assumes that the same good is produced in two countries and that transportation costs are positive. The producers in each country have an incentive to export to the other country (provided transportation costs are not excessive) at a price below the current price. This incentive arises from the fact that sales in the foreign market yield a higher marginal revenue than domestic sales, even though price is lower, as the exporting firm does not suffer a decline in price on the infra-marginal units. The result is two-way trade in identical commodities.

The second and richer set of models rest on consumer preferences which exhibit a desire for variety and on economies of scale in production. These models were developed by Krugman (1979, 1980), Lancaster (1980) and Ethier (1982). The following is a sketch of the simplest model. It closely follows the exposition in Helpman and Krugman (1985). There are two countries (home and foreign), two industries (X and Y), and two factors (capital and labour). One of the industries (Y) uses a constant returns to scale technology to produce a homogeneous good. The other (X) produces a differentiated good. The production of each variety of the differentiated good requires both a fixed and variable cost. It is assumed that the fixed cost is small enough to allow a monopolistically competitive market structure. Technologies are assumed to be the same in both countries and consumers have identical and homothetic preferences represented by the following utility function:

Production of the differentiated good is relatively capital intensive and the home country is assumed to be relatively capital abundant. The home country therefore, imports the homogeneous good and is a net exporter of the differentiated good. Predictions concerning net trade are thus the same as in the conventional H-O-S factor abundance model. However, given the desire for variety in consumption, the home country will both import and export varieties of the differentiated good. The result is intra-industry trade.

Denote the share of home income in world income by s, and home production of the two commodities by x and y. Foreign variables are denoted by a star (*). The price of X in terms of Y is the same in both countries and is denoted by P. Assuming balanced trade the volume of trade equals twice the exports of the home country. Given the structure of preferences, home's exports equal foreign's share of world income (s*) multiplied by the total value of home production of the differentiated good (Px). The volume of trade is thus given by:

The total volume of intra-industry trade equals twice home's imports of the differentiated good:

The share of intra-industry trade in total trade is thus given by:

Given the distribution of income (s and s* held fixed) intra-industry trade will be greater the closer is x* to x, i.e. the closer are the outputs of the two country's differentiated goods sectors. These outputs will be closer, the closer are the two country's capital/labour ratios. Thus, the more similar are the resource endowments of two countries the more important should be intra-industry trade. Similarly, the smaller the size of the capital rich country (i.e. the lower is x) the more important should be such trade. In the limit if two countries are identical (s=s* and x=x*) all trade will be in differentiated goods.

When we move from a 2 × 2 × 2 world to a multi-country, multi-industry and multi-factor world, the exact pattern of trade becomes indeterminate. However, just as in the H-O-S model, the factor content of country i's imports from j will be higher in those factors which in autarky were more expensive in i than in j. While it is not possible to specify exactly which goods i will trade with j, the analysis in Helpman and Krugman (1985) suggests two testable propositions concerning the importance of intra-industry trade in a world of more than two dimensions.

Proposition 1: As a group of countries' resource endowments become less disparate over time, the share of intra-industry trade in the within group volume of trade should increase.
Proposition 2: The closer are two countries' factor compositions, the more important should be intra-industry trade in their bilateral trade.

In addition to resource dispersion, the simple model suggested that the smaller the size of the capital abundant country the more important should be intra-industry trade (provided the monopolistic competition assumption remains valid). This prediction does not generalize straightforwardly to a multi-dimensional world. The model, assuming monopolistic competition in the increasing returns to scale sector, is only a parable for reality. In small countries fixed costs may prevent the establishment of any firm. As Caves (1981) argues, large fixed costs may result in only a single world producer in which case there will be no intra-industry trade. Such cases are, however, relatively rare. Relaxing the monopolistic competition assumption allows a more important role for country size than suggested by the simple model. Two propositions regarding size are:

Proposition 3(a): As the economic size of a group of nations increases, the exploitation of economies of scale is likely to become more pervasive. Providing this does not lead to a further increase in monopolistic production, intra-industry trade should increase.
Proposition 3(b): The larger the size of the smaller country in bilateral trade the more important should be intra-industry trade in bilateral trade.

These propositions are tested in Section 4.

(b) Measurement

Numerous authors have proposed ways of measuring the importance of intra-industry trade. The simplest and most widely used measure is that proposed by Grubel and Lloyd (1975). Intra-industry trade between countries i and j as a share of their bilateral trade in industry k in year t is calculated by:

where Inline Equation represents exports (imports) of good k by country i to country j in year t. To calculate the proportion of intra-industry trade in total trade, we take a weighted average of the individual industry indices where the weights are the share of the industry in total trade. This paper uses 3 digit SITC data so that k = 238. If there is complete specialization across countries the index takes a value of zero. Alternatively, if exports equal imports in all industries the index takes a value of one and all trade is said to be intra-industry trade.

As Aquino (1978) pointed out this measure is biased when aggregate trade is not balanced. Numerous corrections have been applied in an attempt to correct for the bias; however, as Helpman (1987) argues, these corrections are inadequate as the nature of the bias depends on whether the imbalance is generated by homogeneous or differentiated goods. Consequently, we focus our attention on the above measure of intra-industry trade.

(c) Growth and Importance

The shares of intra-industry trade in intra-OECD trade for each country and for the OECD as a whole are shown in Table 3 for selected years. Overall the importance of intra-industry trade shows a steady increase over the period 1965 to 1979, interrupted only in 1974 by the effects of the oil crisis. In contrast, the period between 1979 and 1985 saw no growth in the importance of intra-industry trade, its share in total trade falling by one percentage point over the period. The latest available data suggest an increase over 1986 and 1987. There are significant differences in both the level and growth rate of intra-industry trade across nations. Such trade is highest in the western European nations (Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Netherlands, Switzerland and the United Kingdom) and Canada where it accounts for approximately 50 per cent of total trade. In a number of these countries the share of intra-industry trade has, however, shown little increase over the last 10 years.

Table 3: Intra-Industry Trade as a Percentage of Total Intra-OECD Trade
  1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1987
CANADA 27 37 40 42 47 50
USA 24 32 34 35 37 39
JAPAN 13 19 17 19 19 21
AUSTRALIA 6 5 7 8 9 12
NEW ZEALAND 2 4 6 10 13 16
AUSTRIA 30 36 39 48 50 52
BELGIUM 40 44 50 50 50 51
DENMARK 23 31 33 37 37 39
FINLAND 10 21 24 28 29 30
FRANCE 39 46 50 51 50 52
GERMANY 37 44 47 50 50 52
GREECE 4 7 11 11 13 16
IRELAND 24 30 34 38 38 39
ITALY 31 38 38 40 41 43
NETHERLANDS 38 43 43 45 45 49
NORWAY 20 27 28 29 23 27
PORTUGAL 10 14 17 18 23 26
SPAIN 12 18 23 31 34 39
SWEDEN 28 35 35 42 41 43
SWITZERLAND 33 38 41 49 49 50
TURKEY 3 3 3 4 11 15
UK 27 35 41 46 45 48
ALL NATIONS 28 35 38 41 41 43

Of all the OECD nations Australia has the most highly specialized intra-OECD trade pattern with intra-industry trade accounting for just 12 per cent of total trade in 1987. Australia is closely followed by Turkey (15 per cent in 1987) and New Zealand and Greece (16 per cent in 1987). The degree of specialization in Japanese trade is also low compared to that of most other OECD countries. The other striking observation concerning Japanese intra-industry trade is its failure to increase in the 1970s and first half of the 1980s. In 1969, intra-industry trade's share of total trade was just 19 per cent. Seventeen years later the share was the same. In Section 4 we return to the reasons for this low and static share.

In the 1980s, it has been the less wealthy nations that have experienced the most rapid increases in intra-industry trade. Turkey increased its share by 11 percentage points between 1980 and 1987, Spain and Portugal by 8 percentage points, New Zealand by 6 and Greece by 5 percentage points. These increases compare with a 2 percentage point increase for the OECD as a whole.

Table 4 presents the weighted average share of intra-industry trade for each of the 1 digit SITC categories for each country for 1987. The table shows that there is significant variation across SITC classes. As expected intra-industry trade is least important in those industries which are thought of as producing relatively homogeneous goods – i.e. mineral fuels and crude materials. Intra-industry trade is most important in chemicals (SITC 5) where in 1987 it accounted for 55 per cent of total trade. The importance of intra-industry trade in the other three manufacturing sectors (SITC 6–8) is just slightly lower at around 50 per cent.

Table 4: Intra-Industry Trade by SITC Classes for 1987
SITC CLASS 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 ALL

0. Food and live animals chiefly for food.
1. Beverages and tobacco.
2. Crude materials, inedible, except fuels.
3. Mineral fuels, lubricants and related materials.
4. Animal and vegetable oils, fats and waxes.
5. Chemicals and related products.
6. Manufactured goods classified chiefly by material.
7. Machinery and transport equipment.
8. Miscellaneous manufactured articles.
9. Not elsewhere classified.

CANADA 36 14 24 15 25 45 40 66 50 34 50
USA 20 7 19 16 27 52 35 41 45 49 39
JAPAN 8 7 4 2 29 49 30 17 37 72 21
AUSTRALIA 9 34 3 6 14 11 13 10 18 34 12
NEW ZEALAND 11 49 4 16 15 18 24 15 29 1 16
AUSTRIA 25 38 24 30 11 52 60 54 52 40 52
BELGIUM 46 50 36 31 48 65 56 47 65 42 51
DENMARK 17 23 27 49 23 44 45 46 47 47 39
FINLAND 20 15 9 16 24 36 27 35 43 25 30
FRANCE 32 22 29 27 38 57 62 57 53 49 52
GERMANY 33 25 28 17 60 63 61 51 51 83 52
GREECE 9 20 18 29 26 11 30 6 11 74 16
IRELAND 26 37 19 19 19 42 53 36 55 39 39
ITALY 19 35 19 24 23 52 53 56 28 8 43
NETHERLANDS 33 32 27 17 52 61 62 54 61 61 49
NORWAY 12 12 27 15 36 50 28 32 25 41 27
PORTUGAL 15 23 9 36 8 28 33 32 16 27 26
SPAIN 18 36 21 36 7 44 50 44 34 33 39
SWEDEN 30 17 14 39 51 57 43 45 45 61 43
SWITZERLAND 26 11 21 6 27 58 60 46 53 33 50
TURKEY 4 2 15 14 16 17 19 24 3 8 15
UK 29 43 22 17 16 61 47 54 64 44 48
ALL NATIONS 27 25 21 19 33 55 50 46 47 52 43
% OF TRADE 7.3 1.3 5.1 4.7 0.3 10.1 17.0 40.7 11.8 1.8  
Δ1965–1987 16 13 6 2 13 16 17 10 10 8 15
Δ1976–1987 8 3 4 0 −1 7 4 0 3 −4 4

The last two rows of the table show the increase in intra-industry trade over time in the different sectors. Over the entire period from 1965 to 1987 chemicals (SITC 5), manufactured goods classified chiefly by materials (SITC 6) and food and live animals chiefly for food (SITC 0) achieved the greatest increases. In the ten years to 1987, over which the share of intra-industry trade increased only slightly, chemicals and food products were the two industry groups which achieved the largest increases. Food products was the only one digit category where all countries experienced an increase. The increase in the chemicals category was largely concentrated in those countries whose trade patterns have traditionally been relatively specialized.