RDP 33 Inflation: Prices and Earnings in Australia Appendix A: Derivation of Theoretical Model

A firm is assumed, in the short-run, to maximise profit defined as[1]

Equation

View MathML

Subject to a production function –

Equation

View MathML

Forming the Lagrangean –

Equation

View MathML

The first order conditions for a maximum of (A.1) subject to (A.2) are given by the following four equations –

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

From (A.4) –

Equation

View MathML

Substituting from (A.8) into (A.5) and (A.6) gives –

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Taking the total differential of (A.7)–

Equation

View MathML

Let yi be the partial differential of Y(SN, ST, DL, Q) where
i = 1, 2, 3 and 4 for SN, ST, DL and Q respectively,
  Inline Equation be the part of the function Yi (SN, ST, DL, Q) which refers only to SN, ST and DL, and
  Inline Equation be the part of the function Yi (SN, ST, DL, Q) which refers only to Q.

(Inline Equation and Inline Equation reflect the assumption that the marginal products are additively separable with respect to the Q component of Yi (SN, ST, DL, Q)).

Using the above notation (A.9), (A.10) and (A.11) can be re-written as –

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Now Inline Equation = Inline Equation(SN, ST, DL); Inline Equation = Inline Equation(Q); etc.

Inline EquationdXi = fi(SN, ST, DL)
and Inline EquationdXi = gi(Q)

where Xi = SN, ST, DL and Q for i = 1, 2, 3 and 4 respectively

Hence, normalising around PN, (A.12), (A.13) and (A.14) can be re-written as –

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

These non-linear functions express SN, ST and DL as functions of Inline Equation and Q. Therefore, it is assumed to be valid to write the following supply and demand functions.

[2]

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

The partial differentials of these functions will not necessarily be constants. In most cases, depending on the specification of the production function, the partial differentials will be some function of SN, ST and DL.

The household is assumed to maximise utility –

Equation

View MathML

Subject to a budget constraint –

Equation

View MathML

As in the case of the firm, the first order conditions can be derived by differentiating the Lagrangean –

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

From (A.24) –

Equation

View MathML

Substituting from (A.28) into (A.25) and (A.26) –

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Dividing (A.27) through by PN gives –

Equation

View MathML

Equations (A.29), (A.30) and (A.31) express DN, DT, and SL as functions of Inline Equation and Inline Equation.

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

As in the case of the functions for SN, ST and DL the partial derivatives of these functions will not necessarily be constants. In fact J1 could change from positive to negative if the SL function was backward bending. However, this probability is assumed not to exist within the relevant range.

The three markets will be examined separately for an equilibrating mechanism. Labour market: defining excess demand for labour as –

Equation

View MathML

gives –

Equation

View MathML

Differentiating the excess demand function, (A.36), with respect to time gives –

Equation

View MathML

For discrete time this equation can be represented as –

Equation

View MathML

Where the dots denote a proportionate rate of change such that –

Equation

View MathML

Setting in accordance with the signs on the partial derivatives in equations (A.20) and (A.34) –

Equation

View MathML

Equation (A.38) simplifies to –

Equation

View MathML

It is hypothesised that wages are set, taking account of expected changes in prices, productivity and taxes, so as to eliminate any excess demand existing at the beginning of the previous period (for fuller explanation see pp. 7–9 of the text). That is, wages are set so that –

Equation

View MathML

which implies that Inline Equation = 0

Where the super-script e denotes expected.

Substituting (A.40) into (A.39) and taking account of the expected changes in prices, productivity and taxes, yields the following behavioural equation for earnings –

Equation

View MathML

For estimation purposes the coefficients in equation (A.41) are assumed to be constant. To simplify the notation let

Equation

View MathML

Equation

View MathML

where a5 and a6 are expected to be negative and the constraints implied by theory are –

a2 + a3 = 1
a5 + a5 = −1
a5 = −a7

The first implies absence of money illusion while the other two arise from the fact that each of the tax variables has a relationship with excess demand for labour that is interchangeable with wages with respect to one or other of firms or households.

In order to estimate the wages equation it is necessary to eliminate two variables for which no observable series are readily available. These are Inline Equation and Inline Equation. To remove Inline Equation the adjustment mechanism in the tradeable goods market (detailed on p.A.10) is anticipated –

Equation

View MathML

so that –

Equation

View MathML

and substituted into equation (A.42). PW is world prices and ER the effective exchange rate.

There are two methods of eliminating Inline Equation

Method 1: As noted by Parkin [8, p.9] a relationship between award wages, prices and productivity can be used to eliminate Inline Equation

Equation

View MathML

Where –

Equation

View MathML

Defining –

Equation

View MathML

equation (A.45) can be solved for Inline Equation and substituted into equation (A.42) to give the unconstrained estimating form –

Equation

View MathML

Imposing the constraints implied by theory –

Equation

View MathML

Method 2: Inline Equation be eliminated by making use of the aggregate price expectations series. Solving (A.46) for Inline Equation and substituting into equation (A.42) yields –

Equation

View MathML

Imposing the constraints –

Equation

View MathML

Goods market: The excess demand for non-tradeable goods is defined as –

Equation

View MathML

Differentiating with respect to time and converting the right-hand side variables into proportionate rates of change (that is, Inline Equation) gives –

Equation

View MathML

gives the following excess demand function –

Equation

View MathML

Using the same price setting hypothesis as the labour market –

Equation

View MathML

which implies that –

Equation

View MathML

and allowing for expected changes in the other variables, yields the following behavioural equation for PN –

Equation

View MathML

Simplifying the notation by letting b1 = Inline Equation ; b2 = Inline Equation ; etc, gives –

Equation

View MathML

Where b4 and b7 are expected to be negative and the constraints on the coefficients are –

b2 + b3 = 1
b5 + b5 = b2
b5 = −b7

In the tradeable goods market domestic excess demand (the difference between domestic demand and domestic supply) is –

Equation

View MathML

After differentiation with respect to time this becomes –

Equation

View MathML

However, while XT is generated by changes in WE, PN and so on, the adjustment mechanism is hypothesised to operate in a different manner to the previous two markets. In those markets the price of the commodity in question was assumed to respond to disequilibrium. However, in the market for tradeable goods any existing excess demand will be satisfied by imports and exports. Pricing in the tradeable goods market (as anticipated in equation (A.43) in the labour market) could therefore be expected to follow world prices adjusted for the exchange rate through international arbitrage (for a fuller explanation of this proposition see text p.10).

That is –

Equation

View MathML

For discrete time period analysis the tradeable price setting process could be represented as –

Equation

View MathML

As mentioned in the analysis of the labour market, series for PN and PT separately are not readily obtainable so that the estimating form for the price sector makes use of the identity (already foreshadowed by equation (A.43)) that the aggregate price level is a weighted sum of PN and PT –

Equation

View MathML

Thus substituting equations (A. 57) and (A.61) for Inline Equation and Inline Equation respectively in equation (A.62) provides an unconstrained estimating form for prices –

Equation

View MathML

Imposing the constraints –

Equation

View MathML

Footnotes

A full list of all notation used is presented in Appendix B. [1]

The production function is assumed to satisfy the second order conditions for H to be a maximum. There are also assumed to be no inferior inputs. [2]